Having reviewed the fall of
Rome, Latouche next turns to the earliest beginning of medieval society and
economy in his book “The
Birth of Western Economy.” He
describes several aspects of this period of transition.
The Migrations
He begins with the earliest migrations:
The Roman Empire recognized two
great Germanic families: the Western Germans who for long centuries had been
settled in continental Europe, and the Northern and Eastern Germans who had
emerged in more recent times from Scandinavia.
There were mentions of immigration into the Roman Empire by
Germanic people as early as the late first / early second century.
…the Germans then gradually and by
progressive stages penetrated into the Empire along the entire length of the limes in ever-increasing numbers….
Eventually, the numbers were significant enough that
treaties were negotiated with Rome, recognizing the various tribes as
“federates.”
…most of the barbarians who
penetrated into the Western Empire came not as conquerors, but exactly as in
our own day…to look for work.
The conquest was not so much a military one; Rome fell as
much due to the apathy of the productive caused by the economic policies of the
state as it did from anything else. What
did the barbarians conquer? They came to
an undeveloped land. The forest was
their enemy; the bogs were their subjects:
He had to wrest from virgin forest,
from moorland and sometimes from bog, the land on which he settled, and the
task of bringing Central Europe into cultivation was a slow and unremitting
process of land clearance which went on until late into the Middle Ages.
Private Property
These migrants apparently did not make the same mistake as did
the Pilgrims of New England. Counter to
the views of some – and built on a faulty reading of historical (but not more contemporary)
sources – the cleared land was not held in community ownership, but in private
ownership.
The historian Fustel de Coulanges
set out to demolish this edifice built on sand….the Franks and other Germanic
peoples from very ancient times practiced individual ownership, and that the alodis frequently referred to in barbarian laws is the
equivalent of the Latin hereditas, and is none
other than the hereditary estate.
There was some land common to the community, primarily
forest land. This demonstrates a rather
sophisticated view of private property – that of homestead. The cleared land was viewed as private property;
the land in an unimproved state was not.
This concept of individual ownership was captured, for instance, in the Salic Law:
What a study of the Salic Law does
bring out…is the strong preference of the Franks for individual ownership…. One single word, which has had an
extraordinary history, symbolizes the sacrosanctity of hereditary property – it
is the word ‘alleu’ [freehold] (alodis). In the very beginning this word stood for the
ancestral home and its appendages.
Subsequently it was extended to include the arable lands.
This freehold of property was an important feature throughout
the Middle Ages, first coming up against resistance in England in the time of William
the Conqueror in the eleventh century, when he
claimed all land as his own, with the nobles as his tenants.
The Birth of the Nobles
The armies of Rome as well as those of the tribes consisted
fundamentally of foot soldiers. This
came to an end when the tribes were faced with enemy horsemen from the Far East.
A horse cannot be equipped or a
horseman armed without money, and the men destined to serve in the king’s host
were expected to possess a certain fortune…. One of the most lasting results of
this revolution in the art of war was that whilst compulsory military service
was not abolished, it no longer applied to everyone…. No longer were all free men soldiers, but
only the richest of them….
These horsemen, these new soldiers, were gradually to turn
into the nobility.
You Can’t Replace Something
with Nothing
Rome was no longer able to govern. The tribes were free from centralized state
control, but this does not mean to suggest that there was no organizing body –
only that is was not a body of coercive state force.
The Church contributed in large
measure to the rescue of town life by fitting her temporal government into the
framework bequeathed her by the Roman Empire, and it will soon become evident
that the cities survived by what amounted to a process of substitution. On rural life too, though for quite different
reasons, her influence made itself felt, and in a manner no less unexpected.
The Church then became a great
administrative body, with divisions based closely on those of the state…. The Church became a moral entity endowed with
juridical power.
As such, the Church was to reap financial benefit, as this
position stimulated the generosity of the faithful. “The goods bequeathed consisted chiefly of
country estates,” and such wealth accumulated toward the benefit of
monasteries, many founded as poverty-stricken establishments. Yet over the course of time – and in the
early Middle Ages – many monasteries had accumulated prodigious wealth.
…kings and nobles lavishly endowed
them with huge tracts of cultivable land in a passion of generosity which
verged on the reckless….
The wealthy donors previously had received from Rome, as
part of the treaties established while Rome still had marginal power, vast
swaths of land – land that proved too large to manage. It was from such sources that the donations
were made. Often, the land was fallow or
forests previously used for hunting.
Credit is due the monks for turning such land into productive ground.
The author attributes this generosity to the guilt of the
wealthy – a hope to buy salvation, to avoid eternal punishment. Whatever the reason, the payment was
voluntary. “Thus the institution of
monasticism acquired in less than two centuries a vast number of estates….” With this wealth, and with the infrastructure
provided by the Church…
…the bishops [took] on a host of
varied responsibilities which in normal times would be assumed by the public
services of the state…
This included the building of aqueducts, assistance to the
poor, and hospitality to travelers and the sick. Notably, the Church did not provide for a
standing army, monopoly over coinage, or monopoly over law and justice.
Religious and ecclesiastical
activity saved the lives of a host of Gallo-Roman cities, the existence of
which was threatened by Merovingian apathy…. The presence of a religious
element ensured the survival of old urban centres threatened with slow decay,
and even brought others into existence.
I mentioned previously this author’s favorable view of state
institutions. A flavor of this is found
in the above statement – regarding the so-called “Merovingian apathy.” It is true that Merovingian society was not
centrally controlled and directed via a coercive state. Where the author views this as a detriment,
it strikes me as a blessed gift.
That the Church (in the context of the times; else other
voluntary institutions) took the place of several state functions should be
expected in a land without a state. You
can’t replace something with nothing (h/t Dr.
North). Individuals within communities
will organize towards outcomes that are found to be beneficial. When done in a voluntary manner, this is the
most glorious of outcomes.
Towns sprung up adjacent to the monasteries; not surprising
given the wealth of the monasteries and the work available to the population. This development was ongoing, continuing even
during the time of the Viking invasions and prior to the reopening of
Mediterranean trade.
From Slave to Serf
Under the Roman Empire the ground
had usually been cultivated by gangs of slaves under the supervision of the master
himself or of a bailiff (villicus). In each villa there was a familia rustica or band of slaves responsible for the
farm work.
Coincident with the decay of Rome, side by side with these
slaves were free workers: some as a result of migration from the failing Roman
cities, some as a result of smaller farms forming together one large farm, and
some set free by will of the owner.
While in some cases these free men still carried the stigma
of the slave, the life was much different – they led a family life, living with
wife and children. Of course, the free
man will work harder than the slave, and such an example is offered by the
author: Saint
Martin riding on his donkey, looking for a suitable bishop for the diocese
of Le Mans, noticed…
…a clerk named Victor working in his own vineyard (in vinea sua
laborans) with great zest and vigour, turning it over with his spade,
and covered in dust from head to foot.
In this milieu comprised of freemen and slaves, the
transition was occurring:
…all in fact lived on the land they
farmed, and without actually owning it thought of it as their
land, and handed it down to their children.
Along with the development of the Noble class, there was an
increase in small farms and small farm holdings held by relatively free men:
…the Merovingian age saw an
increase in the number of small farms and small holdings, and that these
fulfilled, though still imperfectly it is true, the secret longing of every
peasant – to have a plot of land big enough to support a family and which can
be handed down to his descendants.
I have learned that the concept of “ownership” and “property”
can mean different things in different times and places. The characteristic of being able to pass
along property to heirs certainly is fundamental to the concept of “own.”
Summary
The transition from Rome to the Early Middle Ages was not a
sudden change, but occurred over time. It
was not due solely or even primarily to attacking, warring hordes of
barbarians, but driven by the decay of an extended empire, with citizens
accustomed to living from the sweat of conquered slaves. The Romans attempted to prolong the Empire
via inflation, price controls, work rules, and taxation. As the citizens could – and in order to
survive – they left, withdrawing their consent.
They found better prospects outside of the protection of the centralized
state.
At the same time, individuals from the Germanic tribes were
migrating closer to Roman territory, and even within it. Rome negotiated treaties with these tribes in
an effort to maintain some control over the territory. Eventually, the decay of Rome overcame the value
of the treaties.
Via a firm belief in private property and the role of the
Church in a more voluntary form of organization, the roots of the Middle Ages
were formed. The so-called apathy of the
Merovingians was, in fact, the victory of a decentralized, voluntary society.
We will next see Charlemagne’s attempts to centralize this
world. Fortunately, his successes will
not last.
Yet another fantastic write up.
ReplyDeleteYou are making me come here more often. I had to look at the Matt Taibbi write up on my way to comment to this one too.
Thank you, Nick.
Delete