I will begin with my answer: maybe. It depends on the contract. Allow me to explain….
Fractional reserve banking is labeled by some as a
fraudulent practice. Murray Rothbard devotes
a chapter to this in his book, “The
Mystery of Banking.”
First, it is appropriate to define the term fraud. I offer the following definitions from three
different sources; the first from a common dictionary, and the latter two from
two different law dictionaries:
Fraud: deceit,
trickery, sharp practice, or breach of confidence, perpetrated for profit or to
gain some unfair or dishonest advantage.
Fraud: A false
representation of a matter of fact—whether by words or by conduct, by false or
misleading allegations, or by concealment of what should have been
disclosed—that deceives and is intended to deceive another so that the
individual will act upon it to her or his legal injury.
Fraud: the
intentional use of deceit, a trick or some dishonest means to deprive another
of his/her/its money, property or a legal right…. Inherent in fraud is an
unjust advantage over another which injures that person or entity.
Fraud is a difficult term to apply to real-world situations –
one of those “I will know it when I see it” terms. I will offer what I see. I would like to examine the application of
the term “fraud” to various aspects of money and banking.
It is also helpful to define what is meant by fractional
reserve banking:
Fractional-reserve banking is the
practice whereby a bank retains funds equal to only a portion of the amount of
its customers' deposits as readily available reserves (currency on hand at the
bank plus deposit accounts for that bank at the central bank) from which to
satisfy demands for payment. The remainder of customer-deposited funds is used
to fund investments or loans that the bank makes to other customers.
Fair enough. Now, is
it fraud? I offer three cases to assist
in answering this:
Case 1
Let’s start with what began as deposit banking:
I take one ounce of your gold
in deposit and provide a receipt for your gold.
I will hold your gold for you in storage. I will charge you a fee to do so. I will deliver your gold upon demand and
presentation of the valid receipt.
Assuming I do exactly as I state – warehouse your gold for
you – there is clearly no fraud.
However, as warehouse operator, I decide to surreptitiously make
a little extra income on the side. Without
changing any of the terms of our agreement, thus leaving you in the dark, I
change my action:
I then lend out some of your
gold, in order to make an additional profit.
I hope that I am able to meet your withdrawal demands.
This, to me, is the cleanest example of fractional reserve
banking. Is there a fraud here? It seems to me that whether or not I am
always successful in meeting withdrawal demand, there is a fraud. The clearest issue is that I am charging you
for a service that I am not performing. A
secondary issue is that there are two receipts for the same good, providing
each receipt holder with the belief that he has immediate claim on the goods.
Case 2
In this case, consider the following terms:
I take one ounce of your gold
in deposit and provide a receipt for your gold.
I do not charge you a storage fee; I may or may not pay you interest on
your deposit. I give you a receipt
stating that I will deliver to you an ounce of gold upon demand and
presentation of the valid receipt.
Note: I do not state I will store your gold. I charge you no fee for storage. In fact, I even find a way to pay you
interest on your gold. This seems to me
to be a perfectly valid arrangement, to the extent there are willing
participants.
Within the confines of our agreement, I find a contractually-acceptable
way to make a little extra income on the side:
I then lend out some of your
gold, in order to make an additional profit.
I hope that I am able to meet your withdrawal demands.
Is there fraud here?
I never said I would store your gold, and I do not charge you in any
case. Are there two receipts for the
same gold? Yes, but the receipts have conditional
claims. My receipt to the depositor is
clear that I am not storing the gold. As
long as the receipts were properly noted, I see no fraud here.
Case 3
Let’s go one step further:
I take one ounce of your gold
in deposit. I do not charge you a
storage fee, although there may be other administrative fees associated with
your account; I may or may not pay you interest on your deposit. As reflected in our contract, the gold
becomes part of my capital base, allowing me to do with it what I will. I offer you a receipt stating that I will
make best efforts to return an ounce of gold to you upon demand and
presentation of the valid receipt.
This also could be a valid arrangement, given willing
participants. Again, within the terms of
our agreement, I utilize this capital to make additional income on the side:
I then lend out some of my
gold (as it is now part of my capital base) in order to make an additional
profit. I hope that I am able to meet
your withdrawal demands.
Again, there is no fraud here. There certainly are not two claims on the
same gold – the gold is mine, not yours, at least in terms of priority.
Case 3 describes, in very basic terms, the
current banking system. The end of
deposit banking came through a few court decisions in England in the early
1800s. To make a long story short, it
was ruled that deposits made at the bank became property of the bank; the bank
is bound to pay a similar amount in return when demanded. From Lord Cottenham’s decision in the
ultimate case, decided in 1848. From
Murray Rothbard, “The
Mystery of Banking”:
The money placed in the custody of
a banker is, to all intents and purposes, the money of the banker, to do with
it as he pleases; he is guilty of no breach of trust in employing it; he is not
answerable to the principal if he puts it into jeopardy, if he engages in a
hazardous speculation; he is not bound to keep it or deal with it as the
property of his principal; but he is, of course, answerable for the amount,
because he has contracted.
One doesn’t have to like the decision, but law in regards to
deposit banking seems to have been built on this foundation ever since. What is interesting to me is why traditional
deposit banks did not immediately spring up again, in a different form. I guess, to say it differently, why have not
/ cannot private contracts reestablish such a practice?
What are some common objections to these observations?
There are two or more
receipts for the same ounce of gold / it is counterfeiting.
Case 1: This is essentially correct.
Case 2: I suggest not.
There are two receipts, but the receipts are conditional. My receipt to you, the depositor, merely obliges
me to make a best effort to meet your withdrawal demand – I am “answerable for
the amount”, but there is “no breach of trust”.
If I am unable to meet the demand for withdrawal, there may be room for
a civil action, governed by bankruptcy laws.
But bankruptcy is not necessarily fraud.
Case 3: This is clearly not true. Even setting aside that there is no gold
backing today, there are not two or more receipts for the same good. The depositor has given capital to the
bank. The bank has first claim on the
deposited goods, and in default other senior creditors might have priority over
the depositor. Again, the various claims
will be resolved via bankruptcy.
This is precisely what is unfolding before our eyes in Cyprus. Depositors are getting a real-world lesson in
the reality of their deposits.
And specifically to counterfeiting, the Treasury is printing
that which it has authority to print. The
Fed is creating digits for that which it is authorized. These entities are not attempting to pass off
an imitation of an original – they are authorized to make the original, as many
as they desire!
It is Inflationary
Inflation is a tricky matter. Monetary inflation has proven difficult to
measure. I know Rothbard has developed
what is called the “True
Money Supply.” Other economists,
Austrian and non-Austrian alike, hold different views as to what should be
included or excluded.
Measuring the money supply is not so simple. In a world where new and different forms of credit
instruments and digital currency units are created regularly, determining and
agreeing on how to measure the growth as a numeric value is inherently
subjective, it seems to me.
My view
is rather simple – even simplistic.
In a reasonably free market for money, credit, and banking, I am not
sure we would bother with the concern about inflation any more than we would
bother with every other business decision we make. If market participants are not artificially
limited as to options, it seems to me that the choice of currency unit will be
no different that the choice of a grade of steel to a manufacturer – one more
business decision that will have an impact to the P&L and cash flow of the firm. A good choice will result in higher profits;
a bad choice, lower.
So now I return to the objection regarding inflation: the
simple answer is yes, it is inflationary.
However, I find the solution to this problem to be found in eliminating
the monopoly, and not in outlawing otherwise legitimate practices (legitimate, as
is true for Cases 2 & 3).
It is an Unstable System
All systems governing mans’ interactions with other men are
by definition unstable. The issue is: which
system offers the likelihood of the least instability? Some suggest that a 100% gold-backed system
is the most stable system. I will
suggest that a system developed and maintained in a free market will be the
most stable.
Ensuring a 100% gold-backed system will require
enforcement. It is also an artificial construct. To put it bluntly, it is a centrally planned
system.
Where on earth is a centrally planned system, one that inherently
requires force to ensure the plan is obeyed, more stable than a system that is
derived by the market, where market forces ensure that the choices of all
market participants are respected and where errors are quickly found and rooted
out?
The answer is obvious for automobiles, or lemons, or
housing. Why not for money and credit?
Rothbard
and Mises
both have identified the self-correcting feedback of the market on limiting expansionary
credit. Inherently, they admit
inflation, but they find the free-market system quite effective in policing the
credit expansion.
When a market serves nicely as the enforcing mechanism, what
is the justification to introduce non-market based force?
The Depositor is too Dumb to
Understand Today’s Deposit Contract
This may be true. It
is certainly irrelevant. Free markets
mean free markets. If this is true for
what I put in my body, or my choice of clothes, it must be true in my choice of
financial matters. It is also not my
obligation to think for another, nor my right to dictate to another.
There is No Choice but to
Accept the Current Banking Contract
This is mostly, but not completely true. To the extent it is true does not excuse the
person entering into the contract. There
is certainly limited choice, but there isn’t fraud in today’s deposit contract. In any case, there is a choice. Transact with cash. Difficult, though not impossible.
Conclusion
I feel this post is incomplete without noting the following,
for which I am forever in the debt of Joe
Salerno:
Daily
Bell: Do you believe in private fractional banking or should it
be illegal?
Dr.
Joseph Salerno: I am neither a philosopher nor a legal
theorist, but I believe in the absolute right of individuals to enter into any
voluntary contract that they choose. But a contract must be meaningful to be
enforceable. If I pay you for a promise to paint my house red and [at the same
time also] green all over, this is not a contract but an absurdity. Likewise if
I pay you (or even if you pay me) to store my motorcycle in your garage so that
it is always available for me to use it and I grant you the freedom to rent it
out at will. My point is that the deposit contract as modern free bankers
conceive it, is a meaningless fiction. It implies that a sum of money can be
both maintained on deposit for instantaneous withdrawal by the depositor and
lent out to a borrower.
Now I am not saying that a free
banking deposit contract can never be formulated in a meaningful way. But then
it would not be a "deposit" contract at all, but a short-term credit
transaction.
Thus to answer the question you
posed: I do not believe that "private fractional-reserve banking," as
it is commonly understood in debates among libertarians and Austrians today,
should be illegal. It is a self-contradictory concept that could never be
formulated into a meaningful contract on a free market.
I used to maintain that fractional reserve banking, if
developed in the free market, would be acceptable. Salerno changed my mind, although I was not
able to fully grasp it when I first read this statement. The problem is that there can be no
fractional reserve banking in a free market, because such a contract (two
people have equal claim to the same asset at the same time) cannot be
written. It is not meaningful; it is a physical
impossibility.
I conclude that the only way to have true fractional reserve
banking is through the fraud of the warehouseman – by fraud, I mean that the
warehouseman has agreed to one set of terms to store the assets, yet is acting
in a wholly different manner in regards to the assets in his trust.
In today’s banking world, we do not have true fractional
reserve banking. I may not like today’s
deposit contract, but there is no fraud in it.
What we have today is a monopoly in money, credit, and banking – a monopoly
that has virtually, but not completely, disallowed the market-cleansing role
suggested by both Rothbard and Mises. The
delay and prolongation enabled by this monopoly power has ensured that the
bust will be a whopper.
The cause is not fractional reserve banking, but the
monopoly. The proper objection is
simple: eliminate the monopoly.
End the Fed.
(Note: The introduction was modified on 31-Mar-2013)
(Note: The introduction was modified on 31-Mar-2013)
If there were no Fed, then market forces would moderate the excess expansion of credit created by deposit banking. Given that loans are created first and deposits are created out of thin air, is there any difference or does it only insure a greater bust?
ReplyDeleteI am not sure what you mean precisely by your question, so forgive me if I am not answering it directly...
DeleteAbsent backing by the state, bank busts would occur, but without the system-wide risks brought on due to the current monopoly system.
Both booms and busts are much larger under a monopoly cartel than would be true under free-banking, it seems reasonable to surmise.
You described Case 3 as basically our current banking system. I have a question though about the receipt in Case 3. What is this receipt?
ReplyDeleteI am asking because when I open a deposit account, I receive a checkbook. Are you simplifying these actual details by saying that a "receipt" is given by the Bank for the deposit?
Another reason I am asking about Case 3 is that I still believe that it creates an injustice because this banking system creates more claims to the gold deposit than are necessary. The depositor has his claims to that money. The bank lends part of that deposit so the bank's loan customer has his claims. The same one amount of gold but now with multiple claims against it.
“…when I open a deposit account, I receive a checkbook. Are you simplifying these actual details by saying that a "receipt" is given by the Bank for the deposit?”
DeleteYou receive a receipt for the deposit; you also have a checkbook.
“Another reason I am asking about Case 3 is that I still believe that it creates an injustice because this banking system creates more claims to the gold deposit than are necessary.”
What does “necessary” have to do with anything?
“The depositor has his claims to that money. The bank lends part of that deposit so the bank's loan customer has his claims. The same one amount of gold but now with multiple claims against it.”
The nature of the claims is different. If you read what I wrote in case 3, this should be apparent.
It is still confusing. I'll have to study this Case more.
Delete