It is no crime to be ignorant of
economics, which is, after all, a specialized discipline and one that most
people consider to be a 'dismal science.' But it is totally irresponsible to
have a loud and vociferous opinion on economic subjects while remaining in this
state of ignorance.
Murray Rothbard
Forgive me, Murray….
I have read almost none of von Mises directly, yet there is
no single economist that has captured my thinking more than he has. I believe
this is so because Austrian economics fits very naturally into my views of how
man interacts with man. Nothing captures this better than the idea of Human Action.
Humans act. This concept captures so much wisdom on so many levels.
I am not an Austrian economics scholar. As indicated, I have read little of Mises
directly. However, I have an interest in the issues around money, credit, and
banking. As I am a strong proponent of
free-market thinking and an opponent of state-backed interference, I looked
specifically for what Mises had to say about free banking.
This led me to a specific section in Human Action: chapter
17, section 12. Certainly I expect Mises
wrote much more on the subject, and it is likely that I am not capturing the
full intent of his meaning by focusing only on this one section. However, as this section seems generally
supportive of the concept of free-market determined banking, I am satisfied to
end my search here (at least for now). Certainly, one could suggest that I have
found what I was looking for and therefore do not want to look further. This is true. However, as I have yet come
across a good reason to advocate state-enforced regulation in banking, I find
no need at this time to look further into Mises’ writing. In this section, he is quite open to and in
fact advocates a free market in banking and credit, it appears.
Mises covers much ground in this one small section. I will
attempt to capture the key points and properly expand on these. I will break up the analysis and commentary
into four sections, as follows:
1) Competitive, Free-Market
Banking
Mises holds that competitive free banking (no government
intervention or support) is the only proper way to regulate banking.
2) The Risk of Being
"Fooled" Into Taking and Holding Dubious Banknotes
Mises describes the reasons he does not believe this will be
of concern.
3) Bills
of Exchange
Mises describes the inflationary nature of Bills of Exchange
4) Gresham's Law
Mises rightly describes Gresham's Law, with good money
driving out bad if all money trades freely.
Competitive, Free-Market
Banking
But now, we assume further, one
bank alone embarks upon an additional issue of fiduciary media while the other
banks do not follow suit. The clients of the expanding bank - whether its old
clients or new ones acquired on account of the expansion - receive additional
credits, they expand their business activities, they appear on the market with
an additional demand for goods and services, they bid up prices….In order to
settle the payments due to non-clients, the clients must first exchange the
money-substitutes issued by their own - viz., the expanding bank-against money.
The expanding bank must redeem its banknotes and pay out its deposits….The
instant approaches in which the bank will - after the exhaustion of its money
reserve - no longer be in a position to redeem the money substitutes still
current. In order to avoid insolvency it must as soon as possible return to a
policy of strengthening its money reserve. It must abandon its expansionist
methods.
Mises makes a powerful statement here. Leave banks free to
compete. Accept that one or more banks might issue excess credit. Understand
that, as market participants recognize this they will demand instant
redemption. This will force the issuing bank to either reduce the excess or
quickly go out of business before doing much damage. In such an environment, the risk does not become
systematic; no bank becomes “too big to fail.”
Mises does not make any statement advocating the outlaw of
such an expansionary practice, at least not in this section. He is quite clear
that it is the market that will best regulate banks, and that clients of the
expanding bank and especially clients of its more conservative competitors will
be vigilant regarding the bank's risky practices. Additionally, the banks will have reason to
police each other.
This is just as one would expect an advocate of free markets
to consider the situation. Elsewhere in this section he describes how
government intervention inherently results in complacency on the part of market
participants.
But even if the 100 per cent
reserve plan were to be adopted on the basis of the unadulterated gold
standard, it would not entirely remove the drawbacks inherent in every kind of
government interference with banking. What is needed to prevent any further
credit expansion is to place the banking business under the general rules of
commercial and civil laws compelling every individual and firm to fulfill all
obligations in full compliance with the terms of the contract.
Here, Mises states that even a 100% reserve standard, if
backed by the government, does not remove the risks of government interference
in banking. Treat banks as you treat every other business, under general laws
and contract, and the market will regulate the banking industry in a much more
effective manner than would the government.
But, some people may ask, what
about a cartel of the commercial banks? Could not the banks collude for the
sake of a boundless expansion of their issuance of fiduciary media? The
objection is preposterous. As long as the public is not, by government
interference, deprived of the right of withdrawing its deposits, no bank can
risk its own good will by collusion with banks whose good will is not so high
as its own.
A bank’s good name is everything - there is no such thing as
a cushion of reserves that will protect the bank once its good name is
questioned. In this light, Mises states that a bank wouldn't voluntary join
hands with banks other than those of unquestioned integrity. It takes years to
develop goodwill, and minutes to destroy it. Without a good reputation, a bank
in a free-market environment would not last long in the market - a significant
barrier to purposely risky behavior.
Mises also makes no statement against the forming of cartels
– as long as the government does not in some manner deprive the customers from
full and complete exercise of their property and contract rights.
Free banking is the only method
available for the prevention of the dangers inherent in credit expansion. It
would, it is true, not hinder a slow credit expansion, kept within very narrow
limits, on the part of cautious banks which provide the public with all
information required about their financial status. But under free banking it
would have been impossible for credit expansion with all its inevitable
consequences to have developed into a regular - one is tempted to say normal -
feature of the economic system. Only free banking would have rendered the
market economy secure against crises and depressions.
What a powerful statement. In this paragraph, Mises offers
that free banking is the best check on un-backed credit expansion, yet also in
a free market, credit expansion is to be expected, and presumably tolerated
within the context of a competitive market environment. He goes so far as to describe banks that
expand credit “within very narrow limits” as cautious!
These statements are worthy of further examination. Free
banking – unregulated and fully competitive banking – is the best check on
credit expansion. Most would see the opposite. Unregulated banks, it is often believed,
would be most likely to exceed prudent levels of credit and leveraged. The
greed and profit motives in the bankers must be checked by regulation and
government oversight to ensure that prudence is maintained in the sector.
Mises says the opposite – free banking would not go to the
excess of credit expansion with the subsequent booms and busts that are visible
in centralized, state-controlled banking.
A few minutes of reflection offer insight as to why this
would be so. In the current system, we have seen first-hand the privatizing of
profits and the socializing of loss. In such a system, there is no natural
market discipline of potential insolvency that would help regulate the banks. The
possibility of banks runs, historically employed when the reputation of the
bank was in question, has been virtually eliminated with the advent of deposit
insurance, again a creature of the state.
Excesses today, in the cartelized monopoly system,
inherently affect the entire system. However, imagine a system where all banks
are subject to not just profit, but also loss; where contractual terms have the
same meanings as with other everyday businesses; where different banks are free
to institute unique currencies, loan and credit policies, etc. In other words,
imagine banking to be an industry like many others. Profit and loss is the best mechanism created
by man to conserve resources and to curb excesses. Those institutions that cannot efficiently
utilize resources are soon drummed out of business. Such events certainly provide better
discipline than does today’s “heads I win, tails you lose” banking system.
Other than the banking sector, we have no examples of import
where virtually every major company of an industry was at risk of simultaneous
insolvency. Instead we have examples of competition bringing out better quality
and lower costs, tailoring services and products in order to capture specific
market segments, we have trial and error of new products, on a small scale,
thus giving natural opportunity for innovation without introducing systemic
risk.
This is what is in store with free banking. The market –
being all of the customers and competitors of each and every bank – will
regulate each bank. If lending practices are overly lenient, depositors will
reduce exposure to the subject institution.
The second statement is equally important. In it Mises
suggests that it is possible and even expected that some banks will practice
expanding credit. He does not call for government regulation, he does not call
for criminal prosecution, and he does not suggest this “evil” must be avoided
at all costs. He requires that all relevant information regarding the bank’s
financial condition and commitments be public, such that customers have the
opportunity to make informed decisions.
Even on this last point, I suspect that Mises would suggest that the
market would be the best mechanism for making public the right amount of data
and information regarding an individual bank’s practices.
He is perfectly satisfied that, to the extent the practice
must be regulated, the market will regulate the practice. If one institution
gets carried away, the competitive market will limit the damage to the subject
institution and to its customers. He calls for no further punishment or
sanctions.
In other words, at least from my read of this section, Mises
leaves room for credit expansion in a free market banking regime, as long as
fraud resulting from false financial or other documentation is avoided.
Today even the most bigoted
étatists cannot deny that all the alleged evils of free banking count little
when compared with the disastrous effects of the tremendous inflations which
the privileged and government-controlled banks have brought about.
Even today, after the most obvious failures of financial
institutions throughout the world, it is rare to hear anyone make such a
statement. Almost all commentators view more or different regulation as the
answer. After the booms and busts of the
last 100 years of central bank “innovation” and intervention, it would seem
that those who advocate a central bank would be the ones on the defensive, as
opposed to those advocates of free banking.
Dubious Banknotes
A lot of nonsense has been written
about a perverse predilection of the public for banknotes issued by dubious
banks. The truth is that, except for small groups of businessmen who were able
to distinguish between good and bad banks, banknotes were always looked upon
with distrust. It was the special charters which the governments granted to
privileged banks that slowly made these suspicions disappear. The often
advanced argument that small banknotes come into the hands of poor and ignorant
people who cannot distinguish between good and bad notes cannot be taken seriously.
The poorer the recipient of a banknote is and the less familiar he is with bank
affairs, the more quickly will he spend the note and the more quickly will it
return, by way of retail and wholesale trade, to the issuing bank or to people
conversant with banking conditions.
If the governments had never
interfered, the use of banknotes and of deposit currency would be limited to
those strata of the population who know very well how to distinguish between
solvent and insolvent banks.
In these passages Mises makes a valuable point: by their
very nature banknotes will only be used to any great extent by reasonably
sophisticated businessmen, those qualified to make a distinction between good
and bad notes. For many of the rest, they will go to redeem notes quickly, not
being always sure of the quality of the institution behind the note. Inherently, this will diminish the use of
such notes.
Faith in bank notes was increased only as the government
became involved, making users of notes less concerned about the true backing. Government
claimed it became involved only for the good of the poor and less capable
clients...but these were the same people who avoided keeping notes for any
length of time anyway. Of course, the
real reason the government became so involved was to reduce the need for
individuals to properly diligence their bank (thus enabling all sorts of
expansionary banking practices), and reduce the possibility of traditional bank
runs.
We see this same complacency today, for example with FDIC
insurance: how many people think at all about the solvency of their bank?
Absent such "insurance", how long would a troubled bank stay in
business? How much more concerned and therefore sophisticated would depositors
be about the home for their funds?
Here again, Mises does not call for a banishment of any
practice (other than by implication the practice of government interference).
Instead, he sees in the free market certain built-in mechanisms to minimize the
likely abuses by less-than-scrupulous businessmen.
Bills of Exchange
The notion of "normal” credit
expansion is absurd. Issuance of additional fiduciary media, no matter what its
quantity may be, always sets in motion those changes in the price structure the
description of which is the task of the theory of the trade cycle.
Mises makes the statement that there is no such thing as a
"normal" credit expansion. This statement strikes me to mean that
there is no "rule" that can be applied to money supply growth; no
standard increase that can be viewed as normal. No Taylor rule. No Milton
Friedman acceptable range of 3% to 5% per year.
No expansion to (somehow) take into account the “growth” of the economy,
thus growing consistent with economic activity.
Inherently, this must be so. There is no formula that can
better determine the necessary supply of money and credit better than the
market can. The market determines appropriate supply and demand for countless
products, most of which are far more complex than the "product" of
money and credit. Why is it that somehow credit is too difficult to be left to
market forces, when it is nothing more complex than one actor with excess
savings making his savings available to another who requires credit? Compared to building a car or farming a
field, the problem of money and credit is rather a simple one for the market to
solve.
The Banking School taught that an
over issuance of banknotes is impossible if the bank limits its business to the
granting of short-term loans. When the loan is paid back at maturity, the
banknotes return to the bank and thus disappear from the market.
However, this happens only if the
bank restricts the amount of credits granted. (But even then it would not undo
the effects of its previous credit expansion. It would merely add to it the
effects of a later credit contraction.)
Here Mises recognizes that the bank must remain disciplined
in its issuance of notes. The more important point is in the second sentence. Mises makes the point that expansion is
expansion. The negative ramifications of expansion may be limited, due to the
short time window, but it is still expansion, with all of the potential
distortions this will cause.
The regular course of affairs is
that the bank replaces the bills expired and paid back by discounting new bills
of exchange. Then to the amount of banknotes withdrawn from the market by the
repayment of the earlier loan there corresponds an amount of newly issued
banknotes.
The individual notes will disappear in short order when
redeemed, but the expansion does not end. Redeemed notes are replaced with new
notes; thus, the expansion is permanent.
In these few sentences, Mises lays bare what should be
obvious to all about Bills of Exchange. They are expansionary to the money
supply and credit. The expansion, even if of a limited duration, will result in
all the negative consequences of any credit expansion. Further, the expansion
is not limited, as redeemed bills are constantly replaced by newly issued
notes.
Having said this, other than expressing the economic /
monetary risks associated with Bills of Exchange, I do not see Mises calling
for a banning of such a practice. I
concur. In a free market for money,
credit, and banking, participants should be free to transact in whatever manner
they choose.
Gresham's Law
Gresham's Law is often stated: bad money drives out good.
This is incomplete, and an incomplete statement of Gresham's Law. It is more
accurately stated: Bad money drives out good if their exchange rate is set by
law.
I would slightly modify even this proper understanding of
Gresham’s Law. If different "money" is free to trade, without any
hindrance from legal tender laws, tax preferences, etc., bad money will not
drive out good, nor necessarily will good money drive out bad. Different
"monies" will find their value in the market, and will trade.
However, if one money is protected by legal tender, and the
valuation is fixed by government, then yes, the bad money will drive out the
good. All will get rid of the over-valued (by government decree) money, as it
MUST be accepted by the counter-party, and accepted at a value higher than the
market would determine.
Mises addresses this idea as follows:
If, however, the things concerned
are not money-substitutes and are traded at a discount below their face value,
the assignment of legal tender quality is tantamount to an authoritarian price
ceiling, the fixing of a maximum price for gold and foreign exchange and of a
minimum price for the things which are no longer money-substitutes but either
credit money or fiat money. Then the effects appear which Gresham's Law
describes.
If, by decree, the "thing" that is no longer a
money substitute must be accepted not at the discounted value of the market,
but at the inflated value of the decree, this money will always be spent first,
and it will drive the truly "good" money out of circulation. Why
would someone spend a 100 cent dollar when a 90 cent dollar must be accepted by
the counter-party at 100 cents? Bad money will drive out good money.
Mises then addresses what would happen in a free banking
environment, where competing currencies trade freely without legal tender. In
fact, he is for the more the merrier, as in the following:
However, freedom in the issuance of
banknotes would have narrowed down the use of banknotes considerably if it had
not entirely suppressed it. It was this idea which Cernuschi advanced in the
hearings of the French Banking Inquiry on October 24, 1865:
I believe that what is called
freedom of banking would result in a total suppression of banknotes in France.
I want to give everybody the right to issue banknotes so that nobody should
take any banknotes any longer.
He proposes that the good money will drive out the bad. In a
freely competitive environment, where multiple banknotes would be issued, he
sees the entire concept of banknotes disappearing, in favor, presumably, of
good coin.
I think this will be true for the absolutely worst
banknotes. However, it strikes me that most will continue to trade, but not at
face value. Perhaps this is what Mises is getting at with the following:
But if any doubts exist concerning
their prime character, people will hurry to get rid of them as soon as
possible. They will keep in their cash holdings money and such
money-substitutes as they consider perfectly safe and will dispose of the
suspect banknotes.
For safety, people will keep the most secure notes, the
notes issued by banks with the best reputation. They will preferably spend the
suspect notes, or more likely take them to the issuing bank for 100 per cent
redemption. But it is clear, for one
individual to spend the notes he considers dubious, another person must be
willing to accept these. Thus I return to the idea that, in a fee market, the
bad money may not be driven out, but only trade at a value acceptable to market
participants.
Such will be the check on any bank, and this I return full
circle to Mises and free-banking. He sees the market perfectly capable of
"policing" if you will, the various banks participating in the
market. Once the reputation of a bank is in question, notes will be brought to
the bank to be redeemed. Unless the bank is acting properly in its reserves, it
will soon find itself depleted. The end comes quickly when the reputation is in
question.
Based on my understanding of this one section of Human
Action, I conclude that Mises is a supporter of free-banking. While he would not approve of every practice that
might result, he envisions that the free-market is the best regulator of
dubious and otherwise poor practices. To
the extent this conclusion of mine holds true when a broader body of Mises’
work is included, I find myself in complete agreement.
No comments:
Post a Comment