I am no trained economist – not Austrian, not any
other. I have been able to grasp (I
believe) the basics of Austrian economics because the foundations conform to
how I understand the world to work: prices are the unifying common language –
the single most important signal through which man can productively cooperate
with his fellow man; profit and loss sends signals about efficient uses of
resources, and further, determine the allocation of further resources to the
most efficient; value is subjective, made manifest in an objective price;
non-market interventions distort these signals and therefore can only lead to
less-than-optimal results for the greater part of humanity.
Clean, simple, easy to understand – and perfectly
descriptive of the world I see around me every day.
Economics – especially as it is practiced in the mainstream –
causes my eyes to glaze over. Formulas,
econometric models, etc.: I get it, sort
of; if I really spend time I can follow it.
But I look at the world around me – none of the fancy modeling and
formulas conforms to or can possibly capture the way people make decisions
every day.
Worse still, it is painfully obvious that the only benefit
of such a voodoo
science is for the purposes of making policy recommendations – in other
words, modern macro-economics exists only to distort markets via government
intervention.
This is my long-winded introduction to preface my comments
regarding a book by Thomas Piketty, “Capital
in the Twenty-First Century.” I haven’t
read the book, and I won’t read the book.
Too many formulas and models. But,
I will review the book!
At the Amazon link (above), I found a very thorough
review. So I will offer a few comments
regarding the book based on the review.
Just a few.
First of all, a description of the book:
What are the grand dynamics that
drive the accumulation and distribution of capital? Questions about the
long-term evolution of inequality, the concentration of wealth, and the
prospects for economic growth lie at the heart of political economy. But satisfactory
answers have been hard to find for lack of adequate data and clear guiding
theories. In Capital in the Twenty-First
Century, Thomas Piketty analyzes a unique collection of data from twenty
countries, ranging as far back as the eighteenth century, to uncover key
economic and social patterns. His findings will transform debate and set the
agenda for the next generation of thought about wealth and inequality.
Piketty shows that modern economic
growth and the diffusion of knowledge have allowed us to avoid inequalities on
the apocalyptic scale predicted by Karl Marx. But we have not modified the deep
structures of capital and inequality as much as we thought in the optimistic
decades following World War II. The main driver of inequality--the tendency of returns
on capital to exceed the rate of economic growth--today threatens to generate
extreme inequalities that stir discontent and undermine democratic values. But
economic trends are not acts of God. Political action has curbed dangerous
inequalities in the past, Piketty says, and may do so again.
A work of extraordinary ambition,
originality, and rigor, Capital in the
Twenty-First Century reorients our understanding of economic history and
confronts us with sobering lessons for today.
To make a long story short, capital is concentrated to an
extent greater that annual income; left to the market, this concentration will
continue to increase.
Now to the comments from the review. The reviewer is A. J. Sutter on March 17, 2014. The comments really are quite thorough – and even
this much is more than I care to read on this subject….
The book's main thesis is that
economic growth alone isn't sufficient to overcome three "divergence
mechanisms" or "forces" that are in many places returning
inequality in income and/or capital to pre-World War I levels. The main mechanisms
are:
(A)
the historical tendency of capital to earn
returns at a higher rate ('r') than the growth rate of national income ('g'),
which typically sets a constraint on how workers' salaries grow, symbolized by
the mathematical expression, "r > g".
To the extent this is true (and, I am not going to get into
the data), it can be so for two reasons that come to mind:
1)
If, over the long term – interest rates /
discount rates have declined. This seems
plausible: as markets become more efficient and global, one would expect the
price of capital (interest) to reflect this efficiency.
2)
Capital has become more valuable than
labor. This also seems not only
plausible, but both true and valuable. How
much better off is the wage earner because capital is accumulated and
deployed? To ask the question is to
answer it – go back to a subsistence economy and decide.
(B)
the relatively recent (post-1980) widening
spread between salaries, not only between the wealthiest 10% or 1% and the
mean, but even within the top 1%.
Nowhere in the review is there any mention of 1971 – the year
when the reserve currency of the world became uncoupled, the year when no major
international currency was tied to gold.
No mention of the unleashing of full fiat. Perhaps this has something to do with the
divergence – again, assuming that the divergence matters.
(C) an even newer inequality in
financial returns, which correlates r with the initial size of an investment
portfolio -- i.e., different r for different investors.
I have no comment – I am not sure what this means.
In Part IV of the book, TP
considers policy approaches to deal with the three forces of divergence. In
short, the answer for all three is a progressive, annual global tax on capital,
to be set at an internationally agreed rate and its proceeds apportioned among
countries according to a negotiated schedule.
No recommendation to reduce the interventions in the market;
no mention of the distortions caused by the interventions. Just a call for more intervention.
No mention of the value that accumulated capital has on the
standard of living of ALL inhabitants of relatively developed economies.
Capital will be taxed annually. This will be spent, resulting in a net
reduction (relatively) of capital. The
re-allocation of the remaining capital will be in the hands of the politically
connected, and not in the hands of the efficient market producer.
This will only lower the average standard of living.
Theft is never a solution for theft. Additional intervention is not the solution
for previous intervention.
Absent an acknowledgement of the distortions in the market
caused by central banking, lack of free-market money, continuous and increasing
regulation, it is difficult to take this work seriously.
That won’t stop many from doing so – such policy
recommendations are music to the ears of the politicians and the oligarchs whom
Piketty claims to want to attack.
Capital becomes concentrated because of the interest charged on money.
ReplyDeletePut simply, poor people need to borrow money, and rich people or corporations have money to lend. Therefore the poor must pay interest to the rich. Therefore capital becomes concentrated in fewer hands over time. It's an inevitable consequence of the "money as debt" system, with inevitable charging of interest.
Good video by German Professor Margrit Kennedy
http://www.youtube.com/watch?v=QuBy3BzCXwg
Poor people don't "need" to borrow. And if they choose to, who would they borrow from if time value was not to come with a price.
Deletehttp://bionicmosquito.blogspot.com/2013/01/ban-interest.html
http://bionicmosquito.blogspot.com/2013/01/ban-interest-via-democracy-global-force.html
But...if we don't borrow (whoever we are, rich or poor), whatever will we do with all that extra time on our hands?
Delete/sarc
There is a fundamental flaw in analyzing the actions of individuals as if they were parts of a larger organism, i.e. "poor people"; "rich people."
ReplyDeleteA person makes decisions based on ultimate valuations and perceptions of the available means. One person may think interest is "evil" and eschew its utility; another person might see interest as a fair price for the exchange of present funds for future funds. The accomplishment of ends is the only true judge of a chosen means.
As to concentration of capital, there are only two means by which to concentrate capital: 1) serve consumers who voluntarily displace the capital (a tacit acknowledgement of an entrepreneurs' capability of allocating scarce resources); 2) take capital through involuntary, extra-market means by using the force of government to secure a greater market capitalization than otherwise would be gained through voluntary exchange, or, more simply, the outright manipulation of the political means (direct taxation and indirect taxation, otherwise seen as the Cantillon effect of controlling a monopoly currency).
If (1) then it is the result of popular opinion (in the truest sense) of people expressing their preferences through actions (or, means chosen to attain their subjective and ultimate ends.) This is a kind of democracy that dictates social and physical organization through decentralized decision-making, guided by the self-interest of people who are voting with their scarce resources. It is the ultimate expression of humanity, regardless of the value judgments attached to deviations from any individuals preference for particular allocations of resources, that is achieved entirely through non-violent means.
If (2) then it is the result of the arbitrary social and physical organization of one or many who have gained control of the monopoly use of force (the government or state.) It is inherently more wasteful as individuals are forced to allocate scarce resources in ways they otherwise would not have chosen; thus, accurate prices (and the information they represent) fail to disseminate to entrepreneurs who have a harder task of deciding which risks are worth taking and which are not, thus leading to a greater proportion of misallocative endeavors and greater swings in the business cycle.
cont...
ReplyDeleteThe other (and more insidious) difference between (1) and (2) is the incentives created and fostered by the two environments. In (1), individuals have the incentive to take responsibility for their actions and to practice charity with an understanding of the mutual risks taken by other responsible individuals who must allocate their scarce resources in attempts at satisfying ultimate ends. In (2), individuals have the incentive to forgo the risk-taking of the economic means to pursue control of the political means by which they can appropriate (by force) themselves and friends wealth rather than to create it by serving voluntary consumers. This fosters an environment where individuals compete for a fixed "public" treasury. Rather than acting in ways mutually beneficial between two market actors, those who control the political means act at the expense of those who use the private means and an animosity is generated by the fundamental differences in attaining wealth by the different classes of actors: those who force others to dispense their wealth and those who dispense their wealth voluntarily. One class is motivated by entitlement and the other by creative production and this distinction drives an arbitrary wedge between people who otherwise are the same fundamentally human organism.
The only argument against the state of affairs of (1) is the belief that humans are fundamentally "evil, greedy and avaricious" and will pursue their ultimate ends at the expense of less powerful market actors; and, the logical conclusion of this belief is the use of force to keep "order" and make sure everyone behaves.
This begs the question: does it make more sense (1) to build societies around the initiation of force (state government) that determine the boundaries of interaction or (2) to build societies around voluntary interactions and let individuals deal with instances of the initiation of force?
I know what Jesus would do; or Buddha for that matter; Lao Tsu, and just about any worthwhile human being...Aside from the logical implications of the disallocation of information and the incentives for abusing and expanding non-productive power, it would seem inevitable that eventually humans try and deal with life as it appears to all of us: one human perspective at a time.
If you don't believe me, perhaps I can interest you in a nap; the bed does not fit everybody perfectly, but I have ways of making things work...
Ban the ability of private FRBs to create money. Says renowned economic commentator Martin Wolf. End cycilical depressions caused by private FRBs and reduce the tax burden on ordinary people
ReplyDelete[quote]
But it would bring huge advantages. It would be possible to increase the money supply without encouraging people to borrow to the hilt. It would end “too big to fail” in banking. It would also transfer seignorage – the benefits from creating money – to the public.[/quote] http://www.ft.com/cms/s/0/7f000b18-ca44-11e3-bb92-00144feabdc0.html#axzz30O5ggjqV
Nonsense - more regulation to deal with the ills of prior regulation.
DeleteOn the one hand, I would imagine that the main driver of increasingly extreme inequalities in wealth is the fact that, when banks make loans, they conjure the money for the loans out of thin air.
ReplyDeleteOn the other hand, why does wealth inequality matter to so many people? It's as if they see wealth as a zero-sum game (which it isn't).