Clive Crook has written a column at Bloomberg, entitled “You
Pick: a Strong Recovery or an Accountable Fed?”
Right off the bat, he gets my attention with another false choice
offered by another mainstream columnist writing another column in an attempt to
protect central banking by keeping the boundaries of the discussion within the
limits set by the masters. I can’t even
get to the article without first struggling through the illogic of the
headline:
- Why should I, or anyone, have the power to make such a “pick”?
- Why are these two possibilities represented as mutually exclusive?
- Is it not possible, in our current economic framework, that we get neither?
- Are there no other choices?
Let’s see what Clive has to say (forgive my use of his first
name, but to refer to him as “Crook” throughout my comments doesn’t seem
proper).
At last week’s conference of
central bankers in Jackson Hole, Wyoming, the main topic of conversation was
off the program.
In the margins of the meeting, many
of the bankers talked about the threat to their independence posed by meddling
politicians.
This concern is understandable. When a small handful of individuals has
virtually unlimited power and ability to manipulate markets, it cannot be
pleasurable to consider that at least some people are considering to take a
peek behind the curtain. For someone who
enjoys playing god over the lives of billions of people, the job of a central
banker is pretty high up on the list for offering a platform – well above any
elected politician in any office, for example.
Whether or how to impose democratic
accountability on central banking has become the most important question in
political economy, not just in the U.S. but also in Europe and around the
world.
Central banking was established in a manner to circumvent
democratic accountability – on two levels.
First, it was meant to circumvent the political dimension of
democratic accountability. The Federal
Reserve was hatched in secret, and the legislation passed in the dark of night
during the year end. Only recently –
after almost 100 years in operation – has there been even the slightest peak
into its most basic transactions. The actions
must be kept secret, because they cannot stand the accountability that comes
with light. The Fed is the backbone of a
system designed to steal wealth from the productive class. How on earth can such an institution be left
open to democratic accountability?
But second, and on a more important level, central banking
was designed to circumvent the accountability imposed by the marketplace – the most
democratic institution ever created by man.
Money and credit first developed in the market – there was no central
banker interjecting himself in the first trade facilitated by an intermediate
means. Various forms of “money” evolved,
based on acceptance in the local region.
These were tried and tested, further refined via broader patterns of
trade. Credit evolved in a like manner,
with forms developed in the market based on methods proven over time to work
efficiently.
The market, that most democratic of institutions, would ensure
that, over time, the most efficacious and efficient means of conducting and
financing trade were developed. Accountability
in money and credit was no different than the accountability expected of any
trade in any good. Accountability of the
banker and financier was no different than the accountability expected of the
blacksmith or cobbler.
Let’s make a deal. Do
what you said. This is the market, and
the market derived money and credit necessary for its ends. Accountability came in the same manner it did
for all goods, and for the same reason. If
you did not deliver the quality and quantity of product expected and paid for,
you would pay the reputational and eventually the financial consequences.
Central banking was designed to strip away the market
accountability, through the monopoly granted by the politicians – those same
politicians that are to be avoided at all costs by the central bankers meeting
in Wyoming.
Unfortunately, the answer that’s
emerging is unfit for public consumption. We can have proper checks and
balances or good central banking, it seems, but not both.
First, I must strip away one word from this choice being
offered by Clive. There is no such thing
as “good” central banking. Any institution
granted monopoly privilege by the state is a “bad” institution. It is central economic planning. It cannot be “good” in any sense of the word. When the market is stripped of its ability to
discipline and hold an actor accountable, there is no “good” that can come
forth. When competition is not only
discouraged, but disallowed, there is no reason to expect “good” to come
forward from the protected institution.
This is most true when it comes to the issue of money and
credit – always and everywhere one side of every transaction, sometimes on both. Utilizing the services of this monopoly
cannot be avoided in any way by any actor in the market. Even a self-sustaining farmer will at some
point be required to pay some form of tax.
The tax cannot be paid in crop. Therefore,
even this farmer must find a way to secure this money-product borne from
monopoly.
Now, let is look at Clive’s choice once again, without the
offending word:
Unfortunately, the answer that’s
emerging is unfit for public consumption. We can have proper checks and
balances or good central banking, it seems, but not both.
Modified this way, the choice offered is quite correct. We can have central banking or we can have
checks and balances – not the checks and balances of the politicians, but the
checks and balances of the market.
The market, left free, is a most wonderful invention. Prices, freely arrived at, communicate to all
participants the views of the most valued uses of the various goods and
services available. Profit and loss
ensures that the goods and services are utilized in the most efficient manners
available. There is no better system
possible to best meet the needs of the consumer, and to meet those needs in the
most efficient manners available.
Let’s return to Clive:
The idea that central banking could
be kept above politics was never really plausible, but for a long time central
bankers could get away with pretending otherwise.
It is true; this idea of political independence was never
plausible. But it is not true that
central bankers pretended otherwise. One
of the more famous examples is that of Arthur Burns, Fed Chairman during Nixon’s
presidency:
…a year into his term, with the
economy faltering, Nixon tapped Burns to replace William McChesney Martin Jr.,
the Fed chief who had dashed his hopes in 1960. According to Burns biographer
Wyatt Wells, Nixon issued his appointee some blunt instructions: “You see to
it,” Nixon said. “No recession.”
Nixon sure didn’t act as if Burns was independent.
…despite his instructions to Burns,
in 1970 the U.S. suffered a recession, triggering a rise in unemployment to 6
percent, its highest mark in a decade.
Nixon was furious with Burns.
Despite the galloping inflation,
Nixon pressured Burns to loosen monetary policy. White House aides, violating
the central bank’s supposed independence, inundated the Fed with memos on the
need to lower rates. “The pressure that Nixon exerted was unbelievable,” says
Joseph Burns, the late Fed chief’s son. Volcker agrees that it got “very
rough.”
Well, it is only pressure.
Central bankers, men with the wisdom to centrally plan the money and
credit for complex, multi-trillion dollar economies, are certainly strong
enough to withstand political pressure. Men
of steel, I would imagine.
As the economy shifted into a tepid
expansion in ’71, Burns allowed the money supply to expand at an annual rate of
8 percent in the first quarter, 10 percent in the next. This was wildly
expansionary. Allan Meltzer, a Fed historian, says Burns’s policy was partly
attributable to honest miscalculations. (Determining the rate of money supply
growth is fiendishly difficult.)
Not fiendishly difficult; impossible. No single man or committee of men can
accomplish this calculation.
But Meltzer says Burns was also
influenced by Nixon’s bullying. The President alternately flattered Burns and
excluded him, and Burns careened between feisty shows of independence and toadying
displays of loyalty. In his diary, Burns assures the President that “his
friendship was one of the three that has counted most in my life”; a few months
later he is recoiling at Nixon’s “cruelty” and, still later, at his
anti-Semitic outbursts.
Can it be that central bankers are human beings, subject to
manipulation, affected by criticism, concerned about being accepted?
Late in 1971, [Nixon] wrote to the
Fed chief, “You have given me absolute assurance that money supply growth will
be adequate to maintain growth.” Burns scrawled in the margin, “Never gave him
absolute assurance. What nonsense!” But Burns, intentionally or not, delivered
on Nixon’s demand for an expansionary monetary policy.
Apparently, central bankers can be pressured
politically. So much for the option of
political independence. Central banks
are held accountable – they are held accountable by strong-arm politicians and
bankers in back-room deals that cannot stand the light of day. Accountable not to market signals but to
political whims. Clive, however, isn’t the
one to explain this to us.
Clive does stumble upon some truth in his piece:
An independent central bank can
promise to keep inflation low more credibly than a bank directed by a finance
ministry -- i.e., by politicians tempted to pump up the economy for short- run
electoral purposes.
On a scale from 1 to 100 (with 100 being their word is good
as gold), central banks’ credibility when it comes to promises of keeping
inflation low I would rate as a 1. If the
politicians were in charge – the notion of greenbackers – I would rate as a 0. A supporter of central banks might take my
comments and suggest that I believe a central bank can do an infinitely better
job of controlling inflation than can the politicians if the latter were in
charge of money and credit. While mathematically
true, I would suggest a different interpretation.
The rest of Clive’s piece offers praise for even more active
central banking, and suggests the mathematically (let alone politically)
impossible for solutions:
I’m for central-bank activism.
This comes through loud and clear.
Under today’s conditions, with
short-term interest rates at zero, countercyclical fiscal policy has to be
granted a bigger role than usual.
“Countercyclical fiscal policy” means deficit spending. I think Clive hasn’t checked the figures
lately.
This role has two equally important
dimensions, as Fed chief Ben S. Bernanke keeps saying, albeit in prudently
elliptical terms. Budgetary stimulus should be maintained or increased in the
short term, and public debt should be contained and reduced (under the terms of
a plan announced right now) in the medium term.
This is the mathematically (and politically) unsolvable
problem, but one that allows the politicians a free pass – increase deficits
today, but show how you will decrease the debt long term. This is such a naïve statement, yet it is
made regularly by many of the wizards – including Bernanke himself. Without expansion, I offer a few faulty
beliefs behind Clive’s (and Ben’s) desires:
- Government spending does not aid growth; it only consumes resources inefficiently.
- Politicians only live in the short term.
- Any “terms of a plan announced right now” won’t be worth the paper it’s written on, and in any case won’t be binding on any politician in the future.
- The only effective “terms of a plan” that would be credible will have to address military adventurism, Social Security, and Medicare. There is no politician willing to announce this plan.
Clive ends where he began:
You can have textbook checks and
balances, with all political actors held accountable to voters and independent
agencies held to a narrow technical mandate. Or you can have an economy on the
path to recovery. Reluctantly, I’ll take the latter.
An independent central bank (an entity that has not existed)
will not be the source of a path to recovery.
Clive does not offer the proper choice.
We can have market-derived checks and balances on money and credit, or
we can continue with booms and busts and banking designed to enrich the
politically connected at the expense of the productive.
There is your choice.
Joyously, I’ll take the former.
No comments:
Post a Comment