The
Birth of Western Economy, Robert Latouche
Based on this book by Robert Latouche, I have previously
written about the fall of
Rome and the beginnings
of medieval society. Latouche next
moves on to various aspects of the decentralized monetary and economic system
of Merovingian society (described as “anarchy” by Latouche), and the transition
toward centralization attempted by Charlemagne – a transition that, fortunately
for those who favor decentralization, did not last for long after his death.
This story is a shining light on a successful period of
anarchy – not Rothbard’s anarchy, but certainly the absence of a centralized
state acting as sovereign. This
possibility was realized as Rome fell, and was reborn after the attempts toward
centralization of Charlemagne and the Carolingian Empire.
Merovingian Decentralization
As previously noted, Latouche is favorable toward state-centralization
– both regarding Rome and later Charlemagne.
Although I disagree with his conclusions, I find his approach helpful;
he has clearly distinguished periods of state-governance from decentralized
governance. In any case, his factual
observations of the economic landscape are priceless.
In the Merovingian period that came after Rome and that
preceded Charlemagne, Latouche notes changes in the monetary systems. During this time, money for daily use moved
from gold toward silver:
The theory that the Merovingians
kept to the gold standard and that the Carolingians replaced it by an exclusively
silver coinage is incorrect and altogether too flattering to the
Merovingians. The reality was less
simple.
It seems to me that the issue has nothing to do with
flattery, but recognition of market forces at work in a less developed economy,
as was the case after Rome. During
Merovingian time, silver became more prominent as the money metal. Most important, this was not by decree of any
king – the Merovingian currency was not controlled by public authorities. Latouche describes this lack of central
control as negligence – in reality it was something more like an open market.
Through the negligence of the
kings, coining in the Frankish kingdom became the monopoly of coiners.
There were multiple coiners; how could this be a monopoly? It is the fact that coinage was by non-state
actors that concerns the author. Latouche
recognizes no government authority outside of state authority. The Merovingian period was a time of
individual and community governance, based on sacred oath and with the Church
as a constant backdrop. There was government;
it just wasn’t government by a state.
After listing the several areas where the Merovingian kings
did not exercise sovereign authority, instead granting “the privilege of
immunity” to “influential laymen,” the author laments…
Never in our history has the conception
of the state known so complete an eclipse.
Numerous churches obtained privileges of immunity; many enjoyed that of
minting money….
That first sentence brings such a smile to my face! Latouche goes on to identify several churches
that held such a privilege of immunity.
What is meant by “immunity”?
Gary North recently
wrote on this subject:
The issue is immunity from state
sovereignty. A declaration of such immunity is a declaration of legitimate
sovereignty.
North cites Robert Nisbet:
So-called diplomatic immunities are
but the last manifestation of a larger complex of immunities which once
involved a large number of internal religious, economic, and kinship
authorities.
This was a normal feature of political life in the Middle
Ages. Again, from North:
Which rights were protected by
medieval institutions, and which were not? Remember, "rights" mean "legal
immunities from governments." It means the right of self-government.
The people of the Early Middle Ages before and after
Charlemagne recognized and enjoyed such rights.
Returning to Latouche: he decries the varying weights and
quality of the coinage produced by these multiple Churches – but isn’t this an
expected and natural process of a market?
Multiple producers compete on price and quality. Further, isn’t this to be expected in a
market that, at the time, was quite local – with little need for commonality
from region to region? Eventually, it
seems to me, the market would move naturally toward commonality for the sake of
efficiency as markets developed.
The author describes the evolution from gold coinage to
silver that occurred under the Merovingians:
Under the Merovingians, silver was
minted earlier and on a larger scale than has previously been thought; nor was
it the shortage of gold which finally established its supremacy, but the
preferences of the northern peoples and the requirements of internal trade.
Gold was hoarded.
Given the relatively low value of the traded goods, this would seem to
be reasonable. Silver sufficed for the
trade of the time. It appears the
transition was driven by the market.
This liking for silver coinage
marks an evolution which was taking place during the late seventh century. The gold solidus and even
the triens were on the way out.
Charlemagne and the Push
Toward Centralization
Charlemagne, unlike his Merovingian predecessors, had a powerful
desire to unite an empire. The author
praises the centralizing and law-giving activities of the Carolingian kings.
Pepin the Short, then Charlemagne,
and their counselors, must be given credit for their efforts to reform the
economy at its roots by starting with a purification of the coinage. …the Carolingian monetary system…was
monometallic, the silver denier, of good weight and alloy…. This reform was not
empirical but systematic and the rulers imposed it on their peoples by a series
of hard-hitting Capitularies.
The system was “imposed” by “hard-hitting
Capitularies.” This seems rather
coercive….
The basic and most vital feature of
these reforms was the generalization of the silver standard which was made
compulsory.
It is interesting to note: Charlemagne attempted to take
advantage of the consolidation toward silver that was already occurring
naturally in the marketplace. The market
was moving in this direction anyway:
In actual fact things had been
moving in that direction for more than a century past, for the percentage of
gold in the solidus and the triens had become so insignificant
that these coins were discredited and almost wholly supplanted in circulation
by the Merovingian denier.
The state only took over what the market had previously
created.
Charlemagne’s great merit lay in
legalizing the existing situation and giving it his blessing….
The market seemed to be doing just fine, without the “blessing”
of a usurper. What glory can be rightly claimed
in a transition that was already occurring?
The market was not developed sufficiently to require gold as money.
…it would have been absurd to put
large quantities, or even quite a small amount, of gold into circulation to
supply markets which were essentially agrarian and handled only modest
transactions.
But of course the market figured this out already. Charlemagne’s coercion in the coin was not
necessary, at least not for market reasons.
The Carolingians strove to maintain
its legal weight and percentage of pure silver in order to prevent it from
becoming a mere token money, a coinage of inflation, and took vigorous, even
unpopular, steps to impose it on their subjects and encourage its circulation.
If the Carolingian coin was superior (not “mere token
money”), why did Charlemagne have to “impose” this on the people? Why was the coinage unpopular? Is it possible that these people of the
Middle Ages understood the danger of sovereign control over the coin?
Further Capitularies were issued in the period 794 to 864
(extending past Charlemagne’s reign); these forced subjects to accept payment
in the state’s coinage – legal tender laws.
However, offenders were numerous, as evidenced by the multitude of
instructions given to the public in hope of breaking down the resistance to the
coinage. Of course, state violence for
violations was introduced:
If the offender was a free man, the
fine was 15 solidi; the fine was a beating if
the offender was a serf.
Nothing changes – the powerful get a slap on the wrist, the
meek get many slaps.
This lamentable reversion [after
the demise of the Carolingian Empire] to the mistakes of the Merovingian era
were all the easier since both Charlemagne, with all his prestige, and also his
immediate successors, had great difficulty in getting these currency reforms
accepted. The unpopularity of the
measures showed itself in an obdurate suspicion and refusal to accept the new
coins put into circulation.
But if the measures were so great, why weren’t these
embraced? Why would the people choose to
revert to so-called “mistakes”? Were
they merely ignorant barbarians? Or did
they know to hide from the state?
Charlemagne was determined to keep
the monopoly of coining exclusively for the Palace Mint and right up to his
death persisted in his resolve…. He
failed in his aim, and his successors were too weak to follow up his plan
successfully.
A market-derived and accepted system will survive any one individual’s
demise – the market is far greater than any one man. It does not require force. It does not require strong political leaders. It merely requires a market.
More Central Planning
Charlemagne’s attempts at control through coercion were not
limited to the coin. In 789, Charlemagne
published the Admonitia generalis, of which
Clause 81 offers further economic controls:
It concerns the Sabbath rest and
gives a list of menial tasks forbidden on Sundays….Nor are women to do any work
connected with cloth….The list is significant….
He was determined to have an inventory of the assets owned
by the many great estates (the better to tax you with, my dear):
On several occasions he ordered an
inventory to be made of these estates, and the Capitulary known as the Brevium exempla, only a fragment of
which has been preserved, shows us how personal property and real estate were
to be catalogued.
Further centralization and control was attempted in other
areas of economic life:
‘Throughout the whole of the realm’
[Charlemagne] wrote, ‘weights and measures must be identical and accurate.’
The aim was ambitious; different provinces had different
measures. Why would uniformity across an
entire empire be necessary in an agrarian, localized economy? The author provides his answer:
…the human reason which lay behind
this decree [was] to prevent those who sold from cheating or robbing those who
bought.
Is this really so?
The economy was primarily local – everyone knew each other in the local
trade, neighbor knew neighbor. If an
individual cheated, sanction was sure to follow, up to and including expulsion
from the community – tantamount to a death warrant in that society.
It is doubtful Charlemagne was concerned about
cheating. It is more likely he wanted
uniformity to make taxing easier. In any
case, the people did not easily submit.
Wait, There is More
For those who call for a banning of interest, you will find
in Charlemagne a hero:
Christian and even clerical
inspiration are plainly discernible in the rigorous measures taken by
Charlemagne and his successors to forbid the lending of money at interest. It had been practiced in the Merovingian
period.
The banning of interest: one of many monetary crank theories
only
possible through the power of state coercion. The Biblical basis for the banning of
interest was not (and most certainly is not) a settled matter; Gary North, to
name the one person who has more thoroughly studied the Bible for economic
principles, proposes no
such ban (see chapter 7). The Bishop of Verdun, apparently, saw no problem with
interest either:
This bishop regarded the payment of
interest as the natural accomplishment of the loan, and as an ordinary
transaction which was obviously fair and above-board.
The Church forbade clerics to engage in the practice,
however Charlemagne was the first ruler to extend the practice to laymen. Such a change could only be implement by
degrees: first that the ban should apply to laymen, but with no punishment
attached; then, a short time later, and in a time of famine, the term usury was
defined in significant detail, through the Capitulary of Nijmegen in 806; and
further tightened the clauses in a famine of 809. Finally, in an undated Capitulary (presumably
written after these others), a heavy fine is outlined:
‘We wish no one’, he declares, ‘to
exact any further interest in any circumstance whatever. Anyone who does so will be made to pay the
fine laid down for breaking the ban.’
This fine amounted to 60 salidi.
While not a good reason to disallow a private transaction
for charging interest, it should be kept in mind that in the time of the Early
Middle Ages, there was no heavy industry or large-scale trade – lending was not
typically for the purpose of large capital formation. Primarily, lending occurred in the need of
purchasing current foodstuffs – the borrower was starving and without
alternatives for survival.
In addition to making illegal the means by which a starving
man might be able to acquire foodstuffs, Charlemagne enacted price controls in
an attempt to keep prices at lower levels (note, price controls came coincident
with the issue of his new coins):
That was why, at the Synod of
Frankfurt in 794, Charlemagne, who had just issued his new deniers, fixed in
agreement with the Fathers of the Council the maximum retail price for the main
corn crops.
These price controls covered crops such as oats, barley,
rye, and wheat – eventually on bread as well.
Charlemagne, in an act described as kindness and as setting a good
example, sold his crop at prices even lower than the maximum price. Of course, another way to look at this is
that he was bankrupting the competition, something he could afford to do given
the control he had over the economy….
The price controls were in place both in ‘normal’ times and
in times of famine. You can imagine the
result.
On the pretense of ensuring that transactions were carried
out in an honest manner, Charlemagne, in the Capitulary of 803…
…forbids the sale of gold vases,
silver, slaves, pearls, horses, and other animals at night-time and insists on
such purchases being made in public.
One might view this as an attempt to kill the black (night-time)
market.
It’s ALWAYS About War
The author suggests the reason behind Charlemagne’s actions
– the Church!
In the sphere of economics, as in
all others, his line of conduct was determined by the Holy Scripture and of the
Church Fathers…. It would therefore be pointless to look for an original
economic or political programme in his Capitularies.
But would it be “pointless” to look beyond the Church for a
reason behind Charlemagne’s actions?
Well, no; it isn’t pointless. The
author himself spills the beans, making irrelevant his comment about being
pointless to look for a program:
Side by side with the requirements
of Christian morality went military necessities.
Whoops! Did the
author really mean to write this?
Where’s Laurence
Vance? The church and the military, side
by side!
The Carolingian economy was a war
economy. Each year of Charlemagne’s
reign was marked by a campaign the preparations for which made heavy demands on
the imperial economy…. It is interesting to note that many of the Capitularies
were introduced in the Spring, obviously with an eye to the summer campaign,
and they were intended partly to put the inhabitants of the Empire into a state
of readiness.
North, quoting Nisbet:
If there is any single origin of
the institutional State, it is in the circumstances and relationships of war.
The connection between kinship and family, between religion and the Church, is
no closer than that between war and the state in history.
War. It’s always
about war.
After the Fall: The Return of
Anarchy
This story comes with a happy ending. Carolingian control over markets died,
thankfully, not long after Charlemagne died – his Empire broke up less than a
half a century after its creation. The
author lauds the intent and accomplishments of this Emperor:
The experiment was in fact an
interesting one…a reorganization based on sound Christian morals and not
altogether divorced from military considerations, an economy which was clerical
in inspiration, a war economy from which capitalism was quite deliberately
banished by the general veto on lending at interest.
Sound Christian morals in concert with military
considerations. I really, really need to
find Laurence Vance!
Latouche bemoans this anarchic quality of the period before
and after Charlemagne. He describes the
term “anarchy,” and explains his view of the time:
The word anarchy is here used in
its strict etymological sense: absence of authority and the bankruptcy of the
sovereign state. It was an evil which
had been undermining Gaul and Western Europe ever since the Great Invasions,
and which Charlemagne and the early Carolingians did not succeed in curing. The responsibility for it must be placed fairly
and squarely on the Merovingian rulers.
As regards the bankruptcy of the sovereign state, Latouche
is quite correct. However, is the
sovereign state the only source for governance?
Referring again to North:
Is civil government the only true
government? Does it alone possess legitimate sovereignty? Defenders of the
modern state insist that this is the case, and that it should be the case.
Latouche is one of these defenders, answering
affirmatively. He does not recognize the
sovereignty as exercised during the Merovingian period before and (through its
close relative) after the fall of Charlemagne – a sovereignty exercised at
decentralized levels of society, but not a sovereignty that would look
completely familiar to advocates of free-market anarchy today. For example, there was little concern of
individual rights. Again, from North:
Then what of individual rights?
This was not a major concern in the medieval era. Why not? Because the
individual's rights were defended by institutions other than the civil
government.
Then, quoting Nisbet:
In the medieval world there was
relatively little concern with positive, discrete rights of individuals,
largely because of the differences of political power and the reality of
innumerable group authorities. But when the consolidation of national political
power brought with it a destruction of many of the social bodies within which
individuals had immemorially lived in taken refuge, when, in sum, law became a
more centralized and impersonal structure, with the individual as its unit, the
concern for positive, constitutionally guaranteed rights of individuals became
urgent. European governments may have sought often, and successfully prolonged
periods, to resist claims of individual right, but it is hard to miss the fact
that states (England, for example) which became the most successful,
economically as well as politically, had the earliest constitutional
recognition of individual rights, especially property. In retrospect, however,
we see that it was the sheer impact of the State upon medieval custom and
tradition, with the consequent atomizing and liberating effects, that, more
than anything else, precipitated the modern concern with positive individual
rights.
Today we look back to the political philosophies underpinning
written constitutions as liberating, when in fact these were the result of –
and ensured
the longevity of – the state as the sole sovereign entity to which man, on
earth, could appeal. The Magna Carta is
heralded as a milestone toward liberal society, when in fact it represented the
loss of the limited sovereignty of other, competing institutions.
When there is only the individual against the state,
individual rights become paramount.
However, in an environment of multiple and competing sovereignties the
need is not so great.
Latouche looks at the issue of immunities granted by the
king – immunities that captured this diverse, decentralized sovereignty,
represented by these competing institutions:
The practice of immunity, the
essential aim of which was exemption from taxation, became widespread and this
serious abdication of responsibility reached such vast proportions that it soon
went far beyond the realm of finance.
Vast tracts of the kingdom were completely outside the jurisdiction of
the central authority, since the king expressly forbade his officials to enter
the immunists’ domains for the purposes of carrying out their administrative
duties.
Did the king grant immunity against his well-being? Not likely.
In many ways, the king was equal to the nobles – the king had no higher
position in the law than did the nobles.
The basis for society was individual, based on sacred oath and grounded
in the teaching of the Church. There was
respect for property. Rights were
defined and respected based on this. The
king had no power to act outside of the old, good law. He was king of a decentralized society, one
not governed solely by a state but by entities based on family, community, and
Church.
Again, from North:
What is the meaning of sovereignty?
It is the lawful, legitimate authority to invade all rival institutions, and to
be immune to invasion by them. In modern thought, it is possessed only by the
State. In this sense, the state possesses what in earlier eras in the West
would have been identified with God. But God's sovereignty was assumed to be
delegated to legitimate institutions: the family and the church. It is also
delegated to the individual. The state's sovereignty is not delegated, except
under stress.
The people of the Early Middle Ages, both before and after
Charlemagne, understood this. They would
cringe in horror at the barbarity of the modern state. From North again, citing Walter Lippmann, who
wrote in 1929:
A state is absolute in the sense
which I have in mind when it claims the right to a monopoly of all the force
within the community, to make war, to make peace, to conscript life, to tax, to
establish and disestablish property, to define crime, to punish disobedience,
to control education, to supervise the family, to regulate personal habits, and
to censor opinions. The modern state claims all of these powers, and, in the
matter of theory, there is no real difference in the size of the claim between
communists, fascists, and Democrats.
This definition, so true today, is completely alien to the
world of the Middle Ages – the so-called Dark Ages. For those looking for an example in history
where state sovereignty was minimal to non-existent, and where life functioned
well and in many cases in a more classically-liberal
fashion (including attitudes toward women and slavery) than in almost any
period under state control, the Merovingians of the so-called Dark Ages and
their post-Carolingian philosophical descendants offer a shining example.
It would be nice to know the silver content and face value of Charlemagnes coins compared to that of the Merovingians since it would be strange of people to be so against the coinage if they thought that it was of good value
ReplyDeleteIf the money had lots of silver and a low face price it would be scooped up by everyone
If the money had an average amount of silver and a fair price it might not be used exclusively but would not need laws to force it on people. The fact that it was issued by the Emperor and was used over a wide area might even give it a slight premium over locally made coins if the silver value was equal
If the money had low silver content for the face value then it would be rejected by the people and only the power of the State could make people use it.
Another problem is the fact that much of the money issued by Charlemagne might never have reached the local economies, his money went to wars and supporting his imperial system so the locals might have had to keep on using their own local money just so they could have money to trade with. There would be little reason for Charlemagne to pay money to local farmers and craftsmen, instead Charlemagne and his followers would be demanding goods from those same people as taxes so they would have little opportunity to get Charlemagnes money. To have money used in trade there has to be trade, not a one way traffic of good to the Emperior and his flunkies.
To rbjmartin: thank you for linking to this article. Also, your replies to the various comments reflect my views.
ReplyDeletehttp://catholicforum.fisheaters.com/index.php/topic,3458706.0.html
Hugo Salinas Price does a really good job explaining why silver is a preferable money for everyday trade and gold for big purchases.
ReplyDeletehttp://www.plata.com.mx/mplata/articulos/articlesFilt.asp?offset=10&fiidarticulo=185
30/March/2012
Silver, liquid and illiquid, the 'modified open mint' and gold & silver as parallel monetary systems
Dennis
Latouche..: "...fixed in agreement with the Fathers of the Council the maximum retail price for the main corn crops."
ReplyDeleteThis is an interesting error. Corn (maize) was introduced to Europe AFTER Columbus made his trips to America...
http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Corn
Dennis Wilson: “This is an interesting error. Corn (maize) was introduced to Europe AFTER Columbus made his trips to America...”
DeleteFrom my post: These price controls covered crops such as oats, barley, rye, and wheat – eventually on bread as well.
From Wikipedia: Corn outside the United States, Australia, and New Zealand means any cereal crop, its meaning understood to vary geographically to refer to the local staple…. Maize is preferred in formal, scientific, and international usage because it refers specifically to this one grain, unlike corn, which has a complex variety of meanings that vary by context and geographic region.
https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Maize
The author was French; the book was originally published in French. He is using the word “corn” as much of the world uses it. The error is not the author’s, and as I listed the corn crops that were being referred to (specifically NOT including maize), the error was not mine.
The confusion of "corn" as synonymous with maize is a common one for those raised in the united state.
Deleteas an interesting aside, the elaborate stone carvings in Rosslyn chapel (a few miles south of Edinburgh), completed before columbus sailed, appear to show cobs of maize...
A likely explaination is - people were already sailing to and trading with North America before Columbus (taking the great circle route from scotland - if the weather's clear, you can do it without loosing sight of land) they just kept quiet about where they were getting the goods from.
From some of my recent reading, there is also the kind of admirable, almost Hoppean, regard by the Merovingians of the role of sovereigns, i.e., to provide governance and not government. There is also the interesting observation that later regimes tried to justify their rule by linking with the Merovingians, most noteably through marriage to daughters related to the dynasty. Most definitely, they did something right.
ReplyDeleteThank you both. MY education on the usage of "corn" has been greatly enhanced--as has my knowledge of the Middle Ages, thanks to these articles.
ReplyDeleteDennis, thank you for stopping by. My education on this subject is not much more developed than yours - it is only as old (and mature) as the first posts I wrote on this topic a few months ago.
DeleteGreat article for our home schooling
ReplyDelete